What the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem is and is not about

In a piece for Bloomberg, Noah Smith wrote:

No. 9. The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem

This is a theory about trade. It says that countries with more capital — industrialized countries such as the U.S. or Japan — will tend to make things that are more capital-intensive. And countries with more labor — such as India — will tend to make things that are more labor-intensive. That’s why the U.S. makes a lot of semiconductors (which require huge fabrication plants), and India makes a lot of clothes.

Tyler Cowen says Noah Smith oversimplified/misrepresented the theorem. He raises four objections, concluding with:

I continue to believe most economists don’t have such a clear sense of the Hechscker-Ohlin theorem. There are so many tricks to HOT I wouldn’t be surprised if I slipped up somewhere myself in this post.

Indeed, I do think Tyler slipped up a bit. He’s right that identifying “effective units” of capital and labor is the relevant exercise and also very difficult (objection #2), and of course the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem is all about ratios, not absolute quantities (objection #3).1

But I want to defend Noah a bit from Tyler’s first complaint, which was:

The HOT proposition is about exports being relatively capital- or labor-intensive, not about production per se. Even for a popular audience, I think that substitution should have been easy enough.

Is that so? Here’s how Ron Jones and Peter Neary stated the theorem in question in their 1984 Handbook chapter, which surely was not aimed at a popular audience:

Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. A country has a production bias towards, and hence tends to export, the commodity which uses intensively the factor with which it is relatively well endowed.

Why does production composition determine net export composition in this model? Well, the factor-abundance theory is a story about economies’ endowments determining the pattern of trade. To talk only about endowments (and thus only about supply-side elements), we have to neuter demand by assuming identical, homothetic preferences.2 Given commodity-price equalization and homothetic preferences, each country has a consumption vector that is proportionate to its share of world income. With no differences in the composition of consumption, differences in the composition of production translate into differences in the composition of net exports, which are simply production minus consumption.

Thus, the prediction about the pattern of trade simply falls out of the prediction about the pattern of production. Here’s how Jones and Neary explained it:

The final core proposition is the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem itself, but this in fact is closely related to the Rybczynski theorem. Consider two countries with different relative factor endowments and the same technology for producing both goods. If both countries face the same commodity prices then, by the Rybczynski theorem, the country with the greater relative endowment of capital will produce relatively more of the capital-intensive good… Provided this production bias is not offset by a demand bias, the relatively capital-abundant country will export the relatively capital-intensive good. When it is expressed in terms of a physical definition of factor abundance, the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem is thus a simple corollary of the Rybczynski theorem…

In terms of the canonical theorem, I think that Noah got that part right. And in a meta sense, Tyler was right as well.


1. When he cites the Leontief paradox, he’s getting into more complicated territory, see Leamer (JPE 1980).
2. In reality, of course, I think that the composition of demand matters!

3 thoughts on “What the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem is and is not about

  1. assafzim

    Great post!

    I too think that Noah was probably more correct focusing on production, but I also think that exports in the model are more than just the result of a convenient assumption about consumption.

    The way I think about the HO framework is that it is a model of how open economies absorb abundant factors, which is very different from what happens in a closed economy. In a closed economy (and in the intuitive thinking of 98% of economists…) the way abundant factors are absorbed is by a decline in their relative price. However, in an open economy, according to HO, this will not happen. Instead, the economy will specialize in industries that make intensive use of the abundant factor. Now, the reason this production effect isn’t the end of the story is the Stolper-Samuelson effect. If an economy produces more of a labor intensive good, and consumes it domestically, this will push down the price of that good, which, according to the Stolper-Samuelson theorem, will lower the price of labor. So, for the HO story to work (absorbing through specialization without a lowering of the price of a factor), the country must export this increase in production of the labor intensive goods.

    So, I agree that HO is about production, and not just about exports. But I also think that the role played by exports is more important for the HO framework than just making the model simple enough to be tractable.

  2. jdingel Post author

    Oh, I completely agree, Assaf. The opportunity to export is crucial to absorbing “excess” production (at given commodity prices). This is the classic point about gains from trade depicted as consuming beyond the country’s PPF. I was merely pointing out the tight connection between the composition of production and the composition of net exports in the canonical theory.

Comments are closed.